Research Article |
Corresponding author: Yannis Katsoulacos ( yanniskatsoulacos@gmail.com ) Academic editor: Marina Sheresheva
© 2024 Yannis Katsoulacos, Zinxhue Gao, Zili Wang, Lingbing Feng.
This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (CC BY 4.0), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original author and source are credited.
Citation:
Katsoulacos Y, Gao Z, Wang Z, Feng L (2024) The role of economics and the quality of antitrust case assessment in China: an empirical investigation. BRICS Journal of Economics 5(3): 5-26. https://doi.org/10.3897/brics-econ.5.e126421
|
This article empirically measures indicators capturing the role of economics in the antitrust decisions of the Competition Authorities of China from 2010 – 2021. The methodology allows that identification of the legal standards (LSs) adopted in assessing different conduct types and their evolution. The LSs are compared to their theoretically optimal level in order to deduce quality of enforcement. Comparative analysis is undertaken with published results on the role of economics for EC’s DGCOMP, UK’s CMA and Russia’s FAS. The Chinese Authorities’ enforcement record lags behind in quality that of DGCOMP and CMA in abuse of dominance cases though it is already well ahead of countries in which their modern Competition Law enforcement started at about the same time (2008), like Russia.
В данной статье эмпирически измеряются показатели, отражающие роль экономики в решениях антимонопольных органов Китая в период с 2010 по 2021 год. Методология включает в себя определение правовых стандартов (ПС), принятых при оценке различных видов поведения, и их эволюцию. Для оценки качества правоприменения правовые стандарты сравниваются с их теоретически оптимальным уровнем. Исследовани использует опубликованные результаты деятельности DGCOMP ЕК, CMA Великобритании и ФАС России для проведения сравнительного анализа роли экономической науки в процессе принятия ими решений. Выяснилось, что правоприменительная практика китайских властей по делам о злоупотреблении доминирующим положением отстает по качеству от DGCOMP и CMA. Однако по этому показателю они уже значительно опережают такие страны, как Россия, которые ввели антимонопольное законодательство примерно в то же время, что и Китай.
antitrust, economic analysis, legal standards, Per Se, effects-based, enforcement quality
антимонопольное регулирование, экономический анализ, правовые стандарты, Per Se, основанные на эффектах, качество правоприменения.
China and Europe share similarities in terms of their law enforcement agencies and institutions given that China has modelled its antitrust regime on that of the EU, which is closest to its own legal traditions. In Europe, administrative agencies are granted the authority to enforce competition law. This mode of administrative law enforcement not only facilitates the regulation of enterprises that engage in anti-competitive practices but also promotes the development of specialized knowledge in competition law and strengthens public trust in competition protection. Similarly, in China, administrative organs possess significant influence over economic development. The legal tradition and the foundation of Chinese legal culture rely on the interpretation of statutory law, the application of legal provisions, and the enforcement of administrative policies. This framework of legal operation aligns with the legal system in continental Europe.
Starting from the mid- to late- 1990s, the EU competition law has underwent a process of modernization, transitioning from a “form (or, object)-based approach” in assessing business practices to an “effects-based approach” (as the optimal Legal Standard, LS). This shift can be attributed to the continuous evolution of industrial organization theory, which questioned the presumption of many conducts, other than horizontal agreements, considered anticompetitive, explained how significant efficiencies can result from these conducts and thus highlighted the increasing significance of economic theory in practical antitrust enforcement. In the United States too, the earliest clause of antitrust law focused on the “per se illegal” rule for price agreements. However, as economic theory advanced, American judicial institutions were the first to become aware of the diverse impacts on the market of business conducts beyond price agreements and, consequently, they adopted the “rule of reason” (the assessment approach referred to as “effects-based” in Europe) for evaluating most of the other business conductss. China’s analysis framework and criteria for enforcing its anti-monopoly law largely draws upon those of the European Union.
In recent literature (
The optimal LSs for evaluating certain violations, particularly vertical agreements and abuses of dominant market positions by individual firms, has for a long time been controversial. During this time, the economic analysis of antitrust has developed greatly, especially with regard to the welfare effects of these actions. Advancements in industrial organization theory indicate that, regarding vertical agreements and exclusive behaviors of individual firms, competition agencies should adopt the legal standard of rule of reason. The analyses of Katsoulacos and Ulph mentioned above, aim to explain and formalize under what circumstances economic analysis, based on this standard, can enhance social welfare and strengthen the deterrent effect of anti-monopoly laws by reducing decision error costs. What had been missing until recently were empirical investigations about whether the actual law enforcement practice reflected the suggestions of economic theory. Our empirical investigation in this paper aims to determine if the economic analysis and legal standards implemented by Chinese anti-monopoly authorities are near or significantly diverge from the optimum level, and how they have evolved over time.
In China, disputes on LSs have mainly focused on vertical agreements (
Such controversies have also characterized enforcement in Europe and the United States in the past. For example, the United States has experienced many iterations in the application of the antitrust Per Se Illegality LS to vertical constraints, especially vertical price constraints. Even after the Supreme Court of the United States established the rule of reason LS in assessing RPM in the Leegin case in 2007, some states still insist on the Per Se illegality LS in RPM cases.
This paper’s main objective is to empirically investigate the role of economics in antitrust enforcement for the case of China. Specifically, whether China’s CAs adopt the economic approach whenever this is the appropriate assessment approach. This is achieved by constructing and then measuring indicators capturing the extent to which the relevant economic analysis and evidence is used by the agency in order to identify anticompetitive behaviour, in the period 2010-2021. The deviation of the Chinese CAs performance is examined, for all the main antitrust conduct categories, from the optimum level, as proposed by economic theory and evidence in at least the last 2 decades (following the developments in theoretical and empirical Industrial Organisation
The measurement of these indicators relies on an updated version of the methodology originally developed by
The dataset distinguishes decisions according to the main conduct types associated with the enforcement of Competition Law. It also contains information about the decisions appealed and about whether or not the decisions were finally annulled by the Appeal Courts.
The structure of the paper is as follows. First, we describe briefly our methodology and the mapping between the assessment screens and the different LSs that we aim to identify using our antitrust infringement decisions database. We distinguish among 8 LSs each one corresponding to a specific level of economic analysis applied in the assessment procedure (including efficiency arguments), as explained in the next section. Then we construct Cumulative Economic Analysis Indicators (CEAI) associated with each decision i.e. indicators that measure the quantity of economic analysis used by the agency in examining anticompetitive effects. We distinguish among four CEAI depending on the extent and type of economic analysis utilised. Decisions are categorised into four main conduct types or groups: hard-core horizontal agreements (G1), other horizontal agreements and concerted practices (G2), vertical agreements and restraints (G3) and abuse of dominance practices (G4). Next, we measure a number of indices. We measure the Weighted Cumulative Economic Analysis Indicators (WACEAI) adopted for each conduct type (the weights being the share of each CEAI used in assessing decisions for each conduct), and the degree of concentration of the agencies’ decisions of each conduct type
We also present indices of the quality of enforcement measuring the extent of deviation of WACEAI from its optimal (i.e. its error minimizing) level for each conduct type relative to the maximum theoretical deviation, as well as an overall index of quality of enforcement by the agencies across all conduct types. With regard to the optimal level of LSs, following the theoretical literature reviewed above, a very broad consensus has emerged in the last two decades among economists that the optimal LS for G1 (hardcore horizontal agreements
Finally, we calculate an indicator that captures the Total Economic Evidence (TEE) considered on average during the assessment of decisions in a given conduct type, irrespective of the burden of proof, i.e. taking into account both the quantity of economic evidence used by the agencies to assess anticompetive effects, as well as efficiency defence arguments by the defendants if the latter are assessed by the agencies. Therefore, TEE is measured as the weighted average of the LSs adopted in the assessment of the decisions of a particular conduct type.
Our analysis shows that, on average, economic analysis has played a relatively small role in the decisions made by Chinese law enforcement officials from 2010 to 2021, and there was little analysis of consumer welfare effects and potential efficiency effects in vertical monopoly agreements and illegal activities that were considered to abuse market dominance. We have found that the quality of law enforcement by China’s antitrust law enforcers needs to be improved. Also, considering the evolution of law enforcement standards over time, we found that there has been no sustained and significant improvement in the quality of competition law enforcement in cases of abuse of dominant positions (enforcement under Article 17 of the Anti-monopoly Law
As already noted, our methodology, begins with the premise that there are variations in the LSs adopted in competition law enforcement, encapsulating the idea that it is best to think of LSs as forming a continuum
Screens | Description |
S1 | Conduct characterisation screen. |
S2 | (a) Market contextualisation and (b) when relevant, Significant Market Power (SMP) /contestability screen. |
S3 | Potential for significant exclusionary impact or enhanced ability to exercise / maintain market power screen. |
S4 | Potential consumer welfare loss, due to just anticompetitive effects, screen. Examination of potential effects on output, prices, quality, variety and innovation. |
S5 | Efficiencies assessment and balancing screen. |
We can then distinguish 8 different LS between strictly Per Se and Quick Look III, as shown in Table
Screens examined in assessment | Legal Standard |
S1 | Strict Per Se (SPS) |
S1 and S2 (a) S1 and S2 | Object – based (EU) Modified Per Se (MPS) |
S1 and S2 and S3 | Truncated Effects Based I (TEB I) |
S1 and S2 and S3 and S4 | Truncated Effects Based II (TEB II) |
S1 and S2 and S3 and S4 and S5 | Full Effects Based (FEB) or Rule of Reason |
S1 and S5 | Quick Look I |
S1 and S2 and S5 | Quick Look IΙ |
S1 and S2 and S3 and S5 | Quick Look IIΙ |
Our dataset consists of the judgment documents of 127 antitrust infringement decisions by antitrust enforcement agencies of China from 2010 to 2021, specifically, from four Chinese antitrust agencies: State Administration for Market Regulation (SAMR; after 2018), the Development and Reform Commission, the Administration for Industry and Commerce, and the Market Regulation Bureau. We also collected data on whether cases are appealed and whether they are reversed (or annulled) by Appeal Courts. Table
G1 | G2 | G3 | G4 | Total |
Total number of decisions(shares) | ||||
69 (54.3%) | 2 (1.6%) | 12 (9.4%) | 44 (34.6%) | 127 |
Number of appealed decisions(shares) | ||||
6 (8.7%) | 0 (0%) | 1 (8.3%) | 2 (4.5%) | 9 (7.1%) |
Number of annulled decisions (shares) | ||||
0 (0%) | 0 (0%) | 0 (0%) | 0 (0%) | 0 (0%) |
As noted briefly above, we classify conducts into four conduct groups (types). These, in more detail now, are as follows:
Conduct group G1: horizontal agreements, which have strong market power-enhancing effects. They include price fixing, bid rigging, boycotts, market sharing and exclusive territories (or a mixture of these);
Conduct group G2: concerted practices - all the decisions that were included here, involved price information exchange cases;
Conduct group G3: vertical restraints, such as various types of resale price maintenance and other vertical agreements such as exclusive dealing or exclusive territories.
Conduct group G4: practices by dominant firms that may have exclusionary effects and hence are considered abusive (such practices include predation, margin squeeze, price discriminations, loyalty rebates, exclusive contracts, tying and bundling and refusals to deal).
From Table
However, it is worth noting that the proportion of appeals is very low, with only nine
As has been noted in
The first measure of enforcement quality we examine is the highest stage of economic analysis present in the decision. Table
The highest level of economic analysis present in the decision | ||||||
S1 | S2 | S3 | S4 | S5 | Total | |
Total number of decisions | 41 | 68 | 12 | 2 | 4 | 127 |
Shares | 32% | 54% | 9% | 2% | 3% |
Table
Type of Analysis Applied Conduct group | S1=1 | S2=1* | S3=1 | S4=1 | S5=1 |
G1 | 69 | 37 | 3 | 0 | 0 |
% within group | 100.0 | 53.6 | 4.3 | 0.0 | 0.0 |
G2 | 2 | 1 | 0 | 0 | 0 |
% within group | 100.0 | 50.0 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 0.0 |
G3 (RPM) | 11 | 3 | 2 | 1 | 1 |
% within group | 100.0 | 27.3 | 18.2 | 9.1 | 9.1 |
G3 (non-RPM) | 1 | 1 | 1 | 1 | 0 |
% within group | 100.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 0.0 |
G4 | 44 | 44 | 12 | 3 | 3 |
% within group | 100.0 | 100.0 | 27.3 | 6.8 | 6.8 |
Total | 127 | 86 | 18 | 5 | 4 |
% of Total | 100.0 | 67.7 | 14.2 | 3.9 | 3.1 |
G3+G4 | 56 | 48 | 15 | 5 | 4 |
% of Total (G3+G4) | 100.0 | 85.7 | 26.8 | 8.9 | 7.1 |
Apart from characterizing the conduct (component S1) which is present in all decisions, a contextual market analysis (S2) also characterizes most decisions (67.7 percent), especially the G3 and G4 conduct types (87,5%). This indicates that in China (as in EC), even in by-object restrictions the Authority must contextualize the conduct taking into account the situation in the market(s) in which it is undertaken.
Table
The result of Table
Number of decisions per conduct group in which different Legal Standards were adopted
Conduct group (share) | Legal Standard | ||||||||
SPS | Object- Based or MPS | TEB I | TEB II | FEB | Quick Look I | Quick Look ΙI | Quick Look ΙII | Total | |
G1 | 32 | 34 | 3 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 69 |
% within group | 46.4% | 49.3% | 4.3% | 0.0% | 0.0% | 0.0% | 0.0% | 0.0% | |
G2 | 1 | 1 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 2 |
% within group | 50% | 50% | 0.0% | 0.0% | 0.0% | 0.0% | 0.0% | 0.0% | |
G3 (RPM) | 8 | 1 | 1 | 0 | 1 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 11 |
% within group | 72.7% | 9.1% | 9.1% | 0.0% | 9.1% | 0.0% | 0.0% | 0.0% | |
G3 (non-RPM) | 0 | 0 | 0 | 1 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 1 |
% within group | 0.0% | 0.0% | 0.0% | 100% | 0.0% | 0.0% | 0.0% | 0.0% | |
G4 | 0 | 32 | 8 | 1 | 2 | 0 | 0 | 1 | 44 |
% within group | 0.0% | 72.7% | 18.2% | 2.3% | 4.5% | 0.0% | 0.0% | 2.3% | |
Total | 41 | 68 | 12 | 2 | 3 | 0 | 0 | 1 | 127 |
% of Total Decisions | 32.3% | 53.5% | 9.4% | 1.6% | 2.4% | 0.0% | 0.0% | 0.8% |
Only one case in G4 is assessed under what we call Quick Look III LS. Under Quick Look LSs the agency presumes without trying to prove anticompetitive effects (so here it does not examine screen S4) but, at the same time, it allows the defendants to provide arguments about the potential pro- competitive effects of their conduct.
CEAI is an indicator of the total economic evidence examined in assessing conducts in a given category by the agency, in order to prove that it is anticompetitive. Thus, for the construction of this index we do not take into account efficiency defense analyses, i.e. economic analyses where the burden of proof lies with the defendants. Below we show the value of CEAI depending on the number of screens assessed (cumulatively).
Screens examined in assessment | Value of CEAI corresponding to screens examined |
S1 | 1 |
S1 and S2 | 2 |
S1 and S2 and S3 | 3 |
S1 and S2 and S3 and S4 | 4 |
The number and share of decisions that correspond to each CEAI are presented, by conduct group, in Table
Conduct group | CEAI | Total | Average Efficiencies Indicator (AEfI) | |||
1 | 2 | 3 | 4 | |||
G1 | 32 | 34 | 3 | 0 | 69 | 0.00 |
Share of decisions for each CEAI (%) | 46.4 | 49.3 | 4.3 | 0.0 | ||
G2 | 1 | 1 | 0 | 0 | 2 | 0.00 |
Share of decisions for each CEAI (%) | 50.0 | 50.0 | 0.0 | 0.0 | ||
G3 (RPM) | 8 | 1 | 1 | 1 | 11 | 0.09 |
Share of decisions for each CEAI (%) | 72.7 | 9.1 | 9.1 | 9.1 | ||
G3 (non-RPM) | 0 | 0 | 0 | 1 | 1 | 0.00 |
Share of decisions for each CEAI (%) | 0.0 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 100.0 | ||
G4 | 0 | 32 | 9 | 3 | 44 | 0.07 |
Share of decisions for each CEAI (%) | 0.0 | 72.7 | 20.5 | 6.8 |
In this table we also present the Average Efficiencies Indicator (AEfI) as the fraction of decisions in a conduct group in which efficiency arguments were used. It captures the frequency that efficiency gains have been claimed by the defendants and subsequently examined by the agency. The results a very low value of AEfI indicating that efficiency analysis plays, until now, a negligible role in Chinese antitrust enforcement.
In Table
The WACEAI and indicators of the quality of enforcement and of legal certainty by conduct group
Conduct group (share) | WACEAI | CEAI with highest share | Concentration index(Max.1) | Quality (Q) of enforcement (Optimal CEAI) | Value of Q relative to max. dev. of 3 | |
G1 | 0.543 | 1.58 | 2 | 0.46 | 2.58(2) | 0.86 |
G2 | 0.016 | 1.50 | 1,2 | 0.50 | 2.50(2) | 0.83 |
G3 (RPM) | 0.087 | 1.55 | 1 | 0.55 | 2.55(2) | 0.85 |
G3 (non-RPM) | 0.008 | 4.00 | 4 | 1.00 | 3.00(4) | 1.00 |
G4 | 0.346 | 2.34 | 2 | 0.58 | 1.34(4) | 0.45 |
WAEQ (Weighted Average Enforcement Quality (WAEQ) of agency) | 2.15 | |||||
WAEQ relative to maximum | 0.72 |
WACEAIj = CEAIji × sji , i = 1, 2, 3, 4, j = 1, 2, 3, 4
where sji are the shares of the CEAIs in each particular conduct group j. The values of WACEAI are interpreted as follows: the higher the WACEAI value the higher the extent of economic analysis utilised by the agency to reach decisions.
The first observation is that, for the conduct group (G1) that is traditionally illegal Per Se (price fixing and market sharing), the WACEAI is, as expected, low. In North American antitrust we would expect the values of WACEAI for G1 cases to be very close to 1 (the optimal value of CEAI along our continuum with Per Se illegality). As can be seen from Table
Secondly, among the cases we have collected, there are two cases of G2 conduct group (coordinated behavior). One case involves the exchange of price information between enterprises, and another one is the division of the market between manufacturers, which involves the exchange of geographical information by the firms. They both should be regarded as horizontal collusion between enterprises, and the optimal CEAI value is 2.
For the G3 (non-RPM) and G4 groups, existing literature has demonstrated that such violations have both the effect of limiting competition and improving efficiency, and antitrust should use comprehensive economic analysis to measure both effects before finding that conduct is illegal. Therefore, the optimal WACEAI value for the G3 (non-RPM) and G4 conduct groups is 4. It can be observed that the WACEAI of the single G3 (non-RPM) conduct shown (Table
Therefore, it can be concluded that in the actual antitrust law enforcement in China, the agencies have utilized appropriate levels of economic analysis of conduct types G1, G2 and G3 (RPM). However, compared with the DGCOMP and CMA, conductsi in the important G4 group, in which we do expect that significant amounts of economic analysis should be used, are assessed using much less economic analysis than is optimal. Compared to China’s WACEAI =2.3, for DGCOMP, for conduct group G4, WACEAT = 3,37 and for CMA it is WACEAI = 4.
The index of the concentration of legal standards (the HHI concentration index calculated as the sum of the squared shares) in Table
Our analysis shows that the index of concentration of LSs used by the antitrust agencies dealing with various conduct groups is at a low level, close to to or lower than 0,5, neglecting G3 (non-RPM) in which we have just one conduct. The concentration is lower than in DGCOM (except for G4) and even lower than CMA
In Table
Qj = 3 − ABS (WACEAIj – CEAIj), j = 1, 2, 3, 4
where CEAIj is the optimal LS for conduct group j and “3” is the maximum possible CEAI deviation and ABS is ‘the absolute value of’.
In Table
In addition, in order to measure the overall enforcement quality of China’s antitrust authorities from 2010 to 2021, we construct the Weighted Average Enforcement Quality (WAEQ) index, using the value of Q for each conduct group with ther respective shares in all the antitrust decisions.
Overall, the enforcement quality of China’s law enforcement agencies is significanlty lower than that of EC and CMA. The WAEQ for EC is 0,86, while for China it is 0,72 (about 16,5% lower). Aad the difference with CMA (where it is 0,91) is even greater. Clearly China’s overall enforcement quality, is low relative to EC and CMA as a result of the lack of necessary economic analysis in the G4 conduct group.
TEE indicates the total economic evidence considered on average during the assessment of decisions in a given conduct group, irrespective of the burden of proof.
For the calculation of the TEE index we treat each of the 5 evidentiary screens identically and assign a value of 1 to the “amount of evidence produced by the screen” if the screen is assessed and a value of 0 otherwise. Obviously the total evidence has a maximum of 5 if all screens are assessed. Subsequently, to each of the 8 LSs we assign a value of the total economic evidence considered by the LS, ranging from 1 to 5 for SPS to FEB, a value of 2 for Quick Look (QL) I, of 3 for QL II and of 4 for QL III.
Note that Quick Look LSs, i.e assessment procedures where the agency did not go through all the components of economic analysis that examine anticompetitive effects before examining efficiency claims i.e. made a quick examination of the pro- and anti-competitive considerations of the allegedly illegal conduct, need to be taken in account. Therefore, the TEE index for each conduct group will be the weighted average of the LSs adopted in the assessment of the decisions of that particular conduct group.
As expected (and as it should be), Table
Index of Total Economic Evidence (TEE) considered during assessment, irrespective of burden of proof, so, taking into account the efficiencies screen
Conduct group | TEE irrespective of burden of proof: Max. 5 | TEE irrespective of burden of proof, relative to maximum: Max. 1 |
G1 | 1.58 | 0.32 |
G2 | 1.50 | 0.30 |
G3 (RPM) | 1.64 | 0.33 |
G3 (non-RPM) | 4.00 | 0.80 |
G4 | 2.41 | 0.48 |
We conclude our analysis with an examination of the evolution of the indicator WACEAI showing the weighted average cumulative economic analysis used in the decisions of each conduct group. Our main interest has been to check whether in the group in which China is performing most poorly (abuse of dominance, group 4) there is a significant improvement. As we see in Table
Conduct Group | 2010-2011 | 2012-2013 | 2014-2015 | 2016-2017 | 2018-2019 | 2020-2021 |
G1: WACEAI | 1.00 | 1.55 | 1.50 | 1.82 | 1.47 | 1.67 |
No of decisions: 69 | 2 | 11 | 12 | 11 | 15 | 18 |
G2: WACEAI | n/a | n/a | 1.00 | n/a | 2.00 | n/a |
No of decisions: 2 | 0 | 0 | 1 | 0 | 1 | 0 |
G3 (RPM): WACEAI | n/a | 1.00 | 1.00 | 1.67 | 1.00 | 2.50 |
No of decisions: 11 | 0 | 3 | 1 | 3 | 2 | 2 |
G3 (non-RPM): WACEAI | n/a | n/a | n/a | n/a | n/a | 4.00 |
No of decisions: 1 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 1 |
G4: WACEAI | n/a | 2.00 | 2.13 | 2.31 | 2.83 | 2.38 |
No of decisions: 44 | 0 | 1 | 8 | 13 | 6 | 16 |
China’s antitrust law enforcement has achieved a very significant progress in the 15 years since its inception in 2008. Of course, it is still in a period of learning and transformation: institutions have been adjusting, so much so that after maintaining a decade long tripartite enforcement structure, the three former agencies were consolidated in 2018 forming a brand new agency (State Administration for Market Regulation, SAMR). Given that competition law legislation was only recently put into place, and the lack of case assessment experience, it is inevitable that when enforcement record is judged in terms of the quality of assessment procedures (as we have tried to do in this article) the “quality” of enforcement will lag behind two of the most advanced and experienced agencies in the world, DGCOMP and CMA. In comparisons with the antitrust enforcement record of DGCOMP, France, Greece and Russia, all 3 countries lag behind DGCOMP (
There are some more reasons that could be responsible for slowing down the adjustment to using more economic analysis for assessment of conduct group G4 in China. The first is that the competition law in China primarily follows the European law and so for enforcement practice Chinese enforcers are likely to be influenced primarily by the EC and EU enforcers (
Another factor is that, as noted above, in China administrative agencies are not constrained by the judicial review system in a way that induces them to adopt assessment procedures in order to satisfy standards, for reaching liability decisions, considered optimal from the point of view of minimizing decision errors, as are the DGCOMP and EU member state or US agencies. This is also reflected in the very low appeal rate, as judged by international standards (i.e. as compared to countries we have examined: EC, UK, France, Greece and Russia) and the zero reversals in the (limited number) of cases appealed (
Finally, account has to be taken of the fact that the creation of economic analysis capabilities in antitrust case assessment is a slowly developing process. And, the lack of economic analysis capability means that the cost of obtaining economic analysis evidence is too high, which tends to force antitrust agencies to an approach of Per Se illegality replacing high administrative costs with relatively high positive error costs, resulting in de facto strict law enforcement. Since the establishment of the State Administration for Market Regulation (SAMR) in China, the enforcement capacity and level of law enforcement have improved. However, the experience and level of law enforcement by various provincial regulatory bureaus are uneven, and their grasp of and ability to implement competition law enforcement standards inevitably varies.
On average, economic analysis has played a relatively modest role in the decisions made by the Chinese antitrust law enforcement agencies from 2010 to 2021, and there was little analysis of exclusionary and consumer welfare effects and potential efficiency effects when assessing conduct for which it is considered important, in the last 2 decades at least, to incorporate this analysis before reaching liability decisions. Thus, after constructing a series of indicators to measure the quality of law enforcement, we found that the quality of antitrust law enforcement by China’s enforcers needs to be improved in the case of conduct types for which it is essential to rely for case assessment on the examination of economic screens that requires the application of economic theoretical and empirical analysis. Considering the evolution of law enforcement standards over time, we found that, unfortunately, there has been no sustained and significant improvement in the quality of law enforcement in the important case of abuse of dominant positions for which the level of economic analysis and quality has been found especially low in the period under examination. Nevertheless, our analysis shows that China’s agencies have been improving their assessment procedures faster than agencies like FAS (the Russian agency) that also started antitrust enforcement at the same time.
The authors confirm that all data generated or analysed during this study are included in this published article. Furthermore, primary and secondary sources and data supporting the findings of this study were all publicly available at the time of submission.
Conduct group | Year | Case |
G1 | 2016 | Linyi Accounting Firm Co., LTD. V. Shandong Provincial Administration for Industry and Commerce |
2016 | Shanghai Haiji Hi-tech Co., LTD. V. Anhui Provincial Administration for Industry and Commerce | |
2019 | Yunyang Yongwang Building Materials Co., LTD. V. Chongqing Market Supervision Administration | |
2019 | Heze Automobile Industry Association v. Shandong Market Supervision Administration | |
2019 | Guizhou Qiandongnan Jinkai Driving School et al. v. Guizhou Development and Reform Commission | |
2020 | 13 concrete enterprises in Maoming City v. Guangdong Market Supervision Administration | |
G3 | 2017 | Hainan Yutai Technology Feed Co., LTD v. Hainan Price Bureau |
G4 | 2020 | Shandong Kanghui Pharmaceutical Co., Ltd. and other lawsuits v. Shandong Market Supervision Administration |
2020 | Qinghai Provincial Minhechuan Cnpc Natural Gas Co., Ltd. v. Qinghai Provincial Market Supervision and Administration Bureau |